Defining Social and Economic Performance Measures for Catch Shares Systems in the Northeast U.S.

Performance measures_338.pdf

Social Impacts of the Implementation of a Catch Shares Program in the Mid-Atlantic

Defining Social and Economic Performance Measures for Catch Shares Systems in the Northeast U.S.

OMB: 0648-0627

Document [pdf]
Download: pdf | pdf
IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

DEFINING SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE MEASURES FOR CATCH SHARE SYSTEMS
IN THE NORTHEAST U.S.
Patricia M. Clay, U.S. National Marine Fisheries Service, Northeast Fisheries Science Center,
[email protected]
Patricia Pinto da Silva, U.S. National Marine Fisheries Service, Northeast Fisheries Science Center
[email protected]
Andrew Kitts, U.S. National Marine Fisheries Service, Northeast Fisheries Science Center,
[email protected]
ABSTRACT
Catch share systems are being encouraged and considered in a variety of United States (U.S.) fisheries. Scientists,
policy makers, and stakeholders (including fishermen and non-governmental environmental organizations) have
different views about potential social and economic impacts and outcomes of these output- oriented systems. Thus
identifying and evaluating impacts over time is essential to assess and improve such systems and determine whether
intended outcomes are realized. During 2009-2010 Social Sciences Branch (SSB) staff at the National Marine
Fisheries Service (NMFS) Northeast Fisheries Science Center (NEFSC) in Woods Hole, Massachusetts engaged in a
multiphase process to identify and define meaningful measures of social and economic performance of catch share
systems, as well as indicators and information sources to guide the ongoing evaluation of these programs. The
principal performance measures identified in this process are financial viability, distributional outcomes,
stewardship, governance, and well-being. Here we review the current state of catch shares in the Northeast U.S.,
describe the methodology used in identifying performance measures and associated indicators, and present the social
and economic performance measure monitoring plan that will guide future investment in social science research at
the NEFSC.
Keywords: catch shares, property rights, social and economic impacts, performance measures, U.S. fisheries
Acknowledgements: Thanks to all the fishermen and other industry and community members, Council members and
staff, and interested academics and policy makers who took the time to answer our questions and provide
suggestions and input on areas we would have missed. Thanks to Julie Olson for providing her manuscript on
privatization, to John Walden for several well-crafted lines on productivity indices, to Eric Thunberg for his
summaries of existing database variables and to the SSB as a whole for all their work reviewing and re-reviewing
the performance measure plan and providing suggestions for improvement. We are also indebted to the Harvard
University Kennedy School Sustainability Science Program for their encouragement and support during early stages
of this project.
Introduction: Catch Shares Gaining Momentum
Property rights regimes for fisheries are not new and have been implemented in a variety of contexts. They typically
involve the allocation of a share of the available fish (quota systems) or a fishing territory (Territorial Use Rights
Fisheries or TURFs), though in industrial fisheries quotas are far more common. A quota share of the Total
Allowable Catch (TAC) can be allocated to individuals or groups (Clay and Olson 2008, Townsend et al. 2008).
Examples range from individual transferable quotas (ITQs) to various community quotas (e.g., Wingard 2000, Pinto
da Silva 2004, Charles et al. 2007, Mansfield 2007, Langdon 2008, Hermansen and Dreyer 2010) to all kinds of
variations in between. A quota can be allocated in perpetuity or annually. It can be granted only as a use right, or
also as a property that can be sold and/or traded. Outcomes may be different for community rather than individual
quotas (Trondsen 2004; Bromley 2005). Recently, instead of property rights regimes some have begun speaking of
“catch shares” (re. Costello et al. 2008, EDF 2009, Meridian Institute 2010), though the two phrases appear to cover
the same range of regimes or systems.
In the U.S. in 2010, under the administration of President Barack Obama and his NOAA Administrator Jane
Lubchenco, catch shares are being highly encouraged as a core strategy to improve the status of environmental
factors such as fish stock status and habitat, and also the social and economic status of communities and individual

1

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

fishermen (see NOAA Draft Catch Share Policy 1 ). Catch shares are a deviation from a previous reliance on input
controls (e.g., trip catch limits, limiting time at sea), and promise to reconnect incentives for conservation via rights
or privilege based management. In this paper we focus solely on the social and economic outcomes of such
programs and how they can best be measured.
Efforts to identify performance measures and track catch share performance are in different stages of development
in each of the six NMFS regions (Northeast, Northwest, Southeast, Southwest, Pacific, and Alaska). While there are
some commonalities in these approaches, differences are intended to reflect the wide range of socio-economic
contexts in which measures are being applied. For the purposes of this document, we restrict our discussion
primarily to the situation in NMFS’ Northeast Region.
Currently 14 catch share plans are in place in the U.S. 2 , constituting approximately 25 percent of the U.S. fisheries
measured by value (NMFS databases). Four of these are in the Northeast: the surfclam/ocean quahog ITQ (Spisula
solidissima/Arctica islandica) (since1990), the Mid-Atlantic golden tilefish ITQ (Lopholatilus chamaeleonticeps)
(since 2009), the Atlantic sea scallop IFQ (Placopecten magellanicus) (since 2010), and the Multispecies
(groundfish) 3 sectors (since 2010). Groundfish is the largest program in number of permit holders and includes 17
group quota or ‘sector’ allocations. Also in the Northeast, at the state level, a pilot sector allocation system began in
2009 in the Rhode Island summer flounder (Paralichthys dentatus) fishery. Other catch share management programs
are being considered and implemented in other U.S. fisheries over the next few years, including additional programs
slated for the Northeast Region.
Need for Social and Economic Performance Measures to Assess Impacts and Adapt Management
Given the significance of this management paradigm shift, and its potential implications for social, cultural and
economic systems associated with regional fisheries, the SSB invested staff time and resources during 2009-2010 to
create a Performance Monitoring and Evaluation Plan and associated research agenda. This dovetails with fishing
industry concerns: “Will sectors perform better than DAS [Days-at-Sea management], and what metrics will be used
to measure this performance?” (Keiley 2010:3). Catch shares have received extensive coverage in the regional press
and been the subject of numerous recent meetings and workshops. This controversy has served as a constant
reminder of the critical importance of careful crafting and implementation of our plan.
The Magnuson-Steven Fishery Conservation and Management Act 4 (MSA) requires U.S. fisheries to adhere to 10
National Standards (16 U.S.C. 1851 MSA § 301) – conserve fish while achieving optimum yield, manage related
stocks as a unit, not discriminate between States, consider economic efficiency, take into account variations between
fisheries, minimize costs, take into account the importance of fishery resources to fishing communities, minimize
bycatch and promote safety at sea, and in the case of fisheries managed under Limited Access Privilege Programs
(LAPPs) (16 U.S.C. 1802 MSA § 3(26)) -- reduce capacity if needed, promote safety and social, economic benefits,
ensure fair/equitable initial allocations, sustain participation of small owner-operated fishing vessels/their fishing
communities, avoid excessive geographic/other consolidation, assist entry-level/small vessel owner-operators,
captains, crew, and fishing communities (16 U.S.C. 1853a MSA § 303A).
In the U.S., Fishery Management Plans (FMPs) are developed by eight regional Fishery Management Councils
(Councils), though final approval must come from the Secretary of Commerce based on input from National Marine
Fisheries Service. Objectives for FMPs vary widely across Councils and across FMPs within Councils, and in some
cases are inconsistent. For instance, within the Northeast Region the goals and objectives for catch share programs
include: control capacity, achieve economic efficiency, encourage diversity of the fishing fleet, minimize adverse
impacts on fishing communities and shore side infrastructure, promote stewardship, minimize bycatch, provide
incentives to self-govern, reduce the need for Council-mandated measures, simplify management, prevent excessive
consolidation that would eliminate the day boat fishery, control fishing mortality, prevent overcapitalization and
limit new entrants, and allow for regulatory flexibility and adaptation.
Additionally, while goals and objectives are defined in the initial stages of the development of an FMP amendment
or framework, this is no guarantee that design elements to achieve these goals are effectively integrated into the
regulatory action. Importantly, after implementation, typically no formal process exists for evaluating whether the
objectives are actually achieved.

2

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

Since many of the stated goals and objectives for these types of management approaches pertain to social and
economic considerations, it follows that social and economic outcomes should be tracked when catch share
programs are implemented. Managers have an obligation to consider how their decisions affect the human context
of the fishery. Where there is success, features of those programs might be emulated. Where problems are
identified, managers need to know what the particular issues are, how things have changed, and what tools are
available to them to address these problems.
Defining performance measures and indicators for the Northeast Region
The process of identifying catch share performance measures and indicators for the Northeast Region began in 2009
and was completed in mid-2010. This plan is not static and will be revisited periodically to ensure that it remains
relevant. The intention of this plan is to evaluate the social and economic outcomes of both catch share and noncatch share fisheries, as it is not enough to know if catch share fisheries provide intended outcomes. We also need to
know whether they perform better on these measures than do fisheries managed under other regimes.
The process of creating performance measures consisted of five steps. Step 1: In May 2009 a group of SSB staff
conducted a literature search and proposed a draft set of performance measures to the SSB as a whole. Step 2:
Between June 2009 and June 2010, this draft plan was vetted in multiple iterations with the full SSB staff and
further refined. Approximately 10 group meetings were held to discuss issues, resolve inconsistencies and reflect on
new information and input coming in from outside sources. Step 3: In September 2009, the SSB held a workshop in
Woods Hole, Massachusetts bringing together key academics from around the country to discuss the draft plan,
debate alternatives and improvements to the plan, and revise and refine it based on a broad range of scientific
experience and input. Step 4: In November 2009, several SSB staff represented the Branch at a national NMFS
workshop on social and economic indicators for catch shares, there providing our input and taking home revisions
based on the national discussion. As a result, components of this plan are consistent with efforts from other regions
and can be compared nationally over time. Step 5: Between October 2009 and April 2010, an outreach effort was
conducted to integrate input from a wide range of stakeholders and ultimately ensure that identified performance
measures were salient and key areas were covered in the emerging plan.
The importance of Step 5, while always understood by us as social scientists, was supported by the GAO (2006)
report finding that stakeholder participation in Council processes has generally been insufficient, and is especially
critical where the development (and in our case assessment) of quota-based fisheries is concerned (re. World Bank
2008:47). The GAO (ibid.) further recommended that NMFS develop a formal stakeholder participation policy
and/or provide the Councils with guidance or training on how to develop and use a strategic approach to enhance
stakeholder participation. To that end, presentations were made to the New England Fishery Management Council
and the NMFS Northeast Regional Office to reach Council members and policy makers. A presentation was also
made to a fishermen’s discussion of catch shares in Portsmouth, New Hampshire (held under the auspices of New
Hampshire Sea Grant and the Northeast Consortium 5 ). The SSB also hosted a wide variety of speakers
knowledgeable about catch share impacts at the NEFSC’s seminar series and used these opportunities to get targeted
feedback on key elements of the plan. Further, we created a website 6 to provide background information to the
public and solicit additional input.
Finally, out of concern that outreach efforts had been focused on individuals who commonly attend and participate
in meetings, the SSB worked with the community outreach group of the Gulf of Maine Research Institute to target
stakeholders less likely to participate in mainstream initiatives 7 . Such groups included vessel crew and shore side
businesses, and were identified via snowball sampling, a special nonprobability method used when – among other
reasons - no good sample frame exists. Initial subjects are identified in a targeted search and later subjects are
identified by initial subjects, until a desired sample size is reached or suggested subjects begin to repeat. Some of the
most repeated comments were on the need to look at crew, not just vessel owners, and the need to track what
happens to people who leave the fishery. Is it by choice? Do they feel forced out? What sorts of livelihoods do
they find after leaving? These efforts were further publicized by a three page article in the regional fisheries
newspaper (Plante 2010).
Guiding Literatures

3

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

How well are people, businesses, and communities doing in relation to a particular fishery? The literature contains
many examples of studies that address specific issues and provide evidence of and theoretical reasoning for cause
and effect linkages. While our choices of indicators are driven by a desire to establish cause/effect, we recognize
there are limitations. Our primary purpose is to measure changes in outcomes that both represent human
“performance” and are likely to be a result, at least in part, of the decisions made by fisheries managers. Research
aimed at improving our indicators and further exploring cause/effect is also a component of the overall SSB
performance measure plan.
To identify the issues to track, we reviewed three major literatures or sources of guidance. These were: 1) U.S.
fishery law and agency policy statements, 2) academic and non-governmental organization (NGO) literature, and 3)
FMP objectives for catch share programs implemented in Northeast U.S. fisheries. The following paragraphs
provide a very brief overview of these sources.
Previous Use of Performance Measures in Fisheries
Social and economic indicators became popular in policymaking in the 1960s (Gruenwald et al. 1997). Researchers
then and since have sought to develop indices that both speak to policy needs and have the academic rigor necessary
to allow meaningful analyses (Smith and Clay 2010).
Fisheries-specific examples include the Jepson and Jacob (2007) vulnerability index (re. Jacob and Jepson 2009), the
Canadian Genuine Progress Index (GPI) (e.g., Charles et al. 2009) focusing on resilience, the Pollnac et al.
(2006[2008]) Fisheries Social Impact Assessment (SIA) Model focusing on well-being, the Tuler et al. (2008)
analysis of vulnerability, the Mahon et al. (2010) approach to governance characteristics of large marine ecosystems
(LMEs), the World Bank (2008) case for fisheries reform, and multiple studies of job satisfaction (see Pollnac and
Poggie 2008 and Smith and Clay 2010, and references therein).
Specific to catch shares, the Environmental Defense Fund (EDF) (2007) developed indicators of performance and
applied them to all U.S. catch share programs. These indicators include measures of compliance, safety, capacity,
season length, boat yields, revenues, employment, and ownership concentration.
One point of interest is that most (though not all) of these indices rely on government data sources (e.g. communitylevel demographic and poverty data, landings, citations issued), which generally provide only objective measures.
This is because “there continues to be a challenge in obtaining socioeconomic and institutional data to develop
appropriate indicators” (Charles et al. 2009:47). Studies have shown that people’s subjective experiences are often
at odds with their objective condition (Brickman et al. 1978; Graham 2009). Thus indices without a subjective
measure may miss important trends as well as differences between groups (Stiglitz et al. 2009; Smith and Clay
2010).
In identifying indicators to use in the Northeast Region, we took care to ensure relevance for fisheries in general.
However, as a point of departure, we began with studies related to documented or claimed positive or negative
impacts of catch shares, given their current relevance and controversy.
Academic and NGO Literature on Impacts of Catch Shares
The economics literature contains a variety of theoretical papers that provide a rationale for why property
rights/catch shares will lead to improved economic outcomes in fisheries (e.g., Gordon 1954, Scott 1955, Clark
1980). There are also multiple case studies in both economics and anthropology (see Shotton 2000 and Townsend et
al. 2008 for two good compendia). Arnason (2008:35) argues that efficiency in property rights regimes derives from
“(i) reduced fishing effort, (ii) reduced fishing capital, (iii) larger fish stocks, (iv) higher quality of landed catch and
(v) better co-ordination between supply of landings and market demand.” But economic impacts are not the only
type of impacts to individuals, institutions and communities, and even economic impacts may not be evenly
distributed across the social landscape due to situational economic and cultural factors (Olson In prep.). While
consolidation may lead to economic benefits, there have been a number of sociocultural concerns expressed
including the distributional equity of such gains. There are concerns that larger scale fishermen will have an
advantage over smaller scale in acquiring catch shares (e.g., Bromley 2005: 224), though this may be due to an
assessment of the number of vessels rather than firms (Brandt 2005). Even where design principles are intended to
limit accumulation by large vessels, this can still occur (McCay 2004).

4

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

Eythórsson (1996:217) finds consolidation in the Icelandic limited access ITQ fleet. The amount of consolidation
was limited, however, because an open access option remained and many small-scale vessels selected this. He also
finds associated land-based jobs decreased and crew income dropped (Eythórsson 2000). Arnason (2008) on the
other hand finds evidence to suggest that Iceland’s ITQ system has created benefits in other sectors of the economy,
as measured by increases in GDP linked to increases in ITQ wealth. And elsewhere Kompas and Che (2003) find
that crew benefited from quota trading in the form of increased share payments. Branch et al. (2006: 1657) also find
income may increase but time at sea also increases – potentially impacting home and community life. Employment
levels for crew generally decrease (e.g., Brandt and Ding 2008: 744) and crew who remain in the fishery may find
their pay system changes from shares to wages (e.g., Bradshaw 2004), changing them from co-venturers to
employees, who have less control over the fishing operation.
In cases where incomes are lower or quota prices are high there can be wide ranging impacts on households and
communities (Pollnac et al. 2006[2008]), including limiting the ability of deckhands to work their way up to captain
(Philips et al. 2002). Other cultural norms may also be changed by limited access or catch shares (e.g., Maurstad
2000). Finally, individual quotas can lead to geographical concentration of quota in larger ports (e.g., McCay 2004),
thus negatively affecting smaller and more rural fishing communities both economically and socially (Lowe and
Carothers, 2009). This is at the same time that some (e.g., EDF 2007, 2009) are promoting catch shares as
increasing profits and sustaining communities. Arnason (2005) finds property essential to economic growth and
efficiency, but notes that rights invested in communities may work better in some cases than ITQs.
Fox et al. (2002) examine changes in profitability according to these components in the British Columbia halibut
(Hippoglossus stenolepis) fishery: output prices, variable input prices, fixed inputs, and productivity. Initial drops
were followed by increases when transferability was introduced. Grafton (1996) discusses the outcomes of ITQs in
terms of changes in fishing effort, profitability, employment in both harvesting and processing, and compliance with
ITQ regulation, generally finding positive outcomes. Geen and Nayar (1989) show increased profitability in the
southern bluefin tuna (Thunnus maccoyii (Castlenau)) industry with an ITQ, despite a severe decline in abundance.
Gauvin et al. (1994) show that post-ITQ prices in the wreckfish (Polyprion americanus) fishery were higher and less
variable due to reduced temporal variability in landings.
Gauvin et al. (ibid.) also find supporting evidence for increased stewardship. Dupont and Grafton (2001:218)
suggest “that rights-based management, since 1993, has encouraged fishers to better allocate their catches over the
fishing season and increased the quality and price for their product.” Costello et al. (2008) claim that catch share
fisheries are less prone to collapse, and from there make the presumption that this shows greater stewardship on the
part of` fishermen. NRC (2003; re. Worm et al. 2009:583) says catch shares may improve compliance – certainly
part of stewardship, though arguably not all of it. Grafton et al. 2006 (re: Johnston and Sutinen 2009 and references
in Olson (In prep.)) suggest more broadly that catch shares may improve ecological stewardship.
Branch (2009), however finds both supporting and contradicting examples for stewardship. Chu (2008), further,
finds little evidence for changes in stock population levels after the introduction of catch shares. Essington
(2010:754) notes that this shows the complexity of factors that influence stock populations, and suggests that catch
shares are not necessarily the key factor (re. Macinko and Whitmore 2009). Essington (2010) himself finds that
catch share fisheries tend to have more predictable and consistent landings but “there was little evidence for higher
population levels, lower exploitation intensity, or increased landings” (ibid., p. 756) - though more stable landings
may mean management is being more effective at maintaining stocks at their TACs or reference points (ibid.).
Further, since many captains are hired rather than being owners, the presumed incentives due to ownership may not
apply (Phillips et al. 2002; Bradshaw 2004; re. Brandt and Ding 2008: 746).
Catch share programs may lead to higher monitoring and enforcement costs for the fishing industry and higher
organizational costs in the case of sectors/cooperatives, but lower costs for government (James 2008). Some have
said safety will be improved (NRC 1999; Sigler and Lunsford 2001; EDF 2007, 2009) but Windle et al. (2008: 707)
find in their review of six different fisheries that impacts of ITQs on safety were mixed.
Final Performance Measures and Associated Indicators

5

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

Based on the review of literature and outreach efforts, we identify five performance measures that consistently
emerged, along with a set of individual indicators on key components of these measures. The five overarching
measures are: 1) Financial Viability, 2) Distributional Outcomes, 3) Stewardship, 4) Governance and 5) Well-being.
While not surprising or particularly remarkable, they largely mirror those identified as critical during other outreach
efforts over the years, such as an effort conducted by the North Atlantic Marine Alliance (NAMA) to identify a
vision for the groundfish fisheries in the Northeast U.S. (NAMA 2005). This suggests that these areas of
performance have been and continue to be salient to a broad range of stakeholders, and key in evaluating the social
and economic performance of catch shares and other approaches to fisheries management. These performance
measures effectively capture the range of concerns within the sociocultural and economic realms, both as overall
concerns for fisheries management in general, and also as areas important to target for studies of catch share
fisheries in particular. Table 1 provides definitions for each performance measure. In Table 2 we provide specific
indicators for each performance measure and a proposed approach for defining each indicator.
We define a “performance measure” as a general issue or outcome related to a management program. Such a
measure may relate to the stated goals of a program, to the requirements of fisheries laws, or to concerns identified
by stakeholders. Together, the five measures are the categories of issues/outcomes that describe the human
dimension of fisheries.
“Indicators” are specific components of performance measure categories that are thought to provide reliable, though
not definitive, indications or supporting evidence that an outcome has changed. For any indicator, several
complementary approaches may be used. For example, stewardship of the resource is thought to be affected by the
implementation of a catch share program, and therefore is included as one of our performance measures. Change in
the amount of by-catch is an indicator of a change in stewardship. However, tracking by-catch alone is not a
sufficient measure of changes in stewardship and other indicators are identified.
Table 1: Performance Measure Definitions
Performance
Definition
Measure
Financial Viability
The financial condition of fishing vessel owners and crew, fishing households, businesses
that provide fishing-related goods and services (e.g., fuel, ice, gear, insurance), and
businesses in the marketing chain (processors, dealers, retailers).
Distributional
The outcomes and implications related to how the benefits and costs of a catch share
Outcomes
program are distributed among individuals, groups, and communities. Major focus is on
access/exclusion to quota and fishing opportunities, concentration of quota, and
employment opportunities.
Stewardship
The degree to which participants use the resource in a careful and responsible way.
Additionally, the degree to which participants have a sense of stewardship.
Governance
The degree to which stakeholders participate in the process of decision-making and
implementation, the transparency and legitimacy of that process, the effectiveness and
complexity of regulations, and the degree of adaptability/flexibility of the management
process. An additional component of governance is the cost to government to implement
a management program and the cost to participants.
Well-being
The degree to which an individual, family, or larger social grouping (e.g., firm,
community) can be characterized as being healthy (sound and functional), happy, and
prosperous (Pollnac et al. 2006[2008]).
Table 2: Social and Economic Performance Measures and Indicators
Financial Viability
Indicators
Proposed Approach (some or all of these may be used)
Profitability and productivity
ƒ Malmquist index* (Technical measure of transformation of inputs into
outputs)
ƒ Capacity utilization
ƒ Revenue per unit effort
ƒ Revenue per active vessel*
ƒ Revenue per vessel day*

6

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

Landings distributions over time
Distributional Outcomes
Indicators
Employment trends

Ownership trends
Price of quota/ability to purchase
quota
Community scale outcomes
Governance
Indicators
Participation in governance
Effectiveness
Transparency/Legitimacy
Conflict
Adaptability/Flexibility
Management costs

Management complexity
Stewardship
Indicators
Compliance
Bycatch/Discards/Highgrading
Conservation ethic
Activities that benefit the stock
Well-being
Indicators
Health status and access to health
insurance
Community level indicators
Port infrastructure
Job Satisfaction
Changes in social networks and

ƒ
ƒ
ƒ
ƒ
ƒ

Lease price*
Share price*
Lease or share price to ex-vessel price*
Fishing capacity of active vessels*
Chart distribution of landings over time

Proposed Approach (some or all of these may be used)
ƒ Total annual fishermen days*
ƒ Employment demographics*
ƒ Total number of active crew*
ƒ Average crew earnings by day*
ƒ Total crew earnings as a percent of net revenue*
ƒ Changes in crew duties/ payment arrangements
ƒ Survey participants about opportunities for new entrants (crew and
owners)
ƒ Industrial concentration (Gini coefficient and Herfindahl index)
ƒ Revenue by vessel type & community/geographic location
ƒ Lease and share prices
ƒ Debt ratio (total debt/total assets)
ƒ Survey participants about ability to purchase quota
ƒ Revenue by communities that depend on fisheries*
Proposed Approach (some or all of these may be used)
ƒ Survey participants about perception of degree of influence, levels of
attendance at meetings, and participation in leadership
ƒ Number of regulatory infractions
ƒ Quota overages*/underages
ƒ Survey participants about perceptions of transparency/legitimacy of
governance systems
ƒ Survey participants about changes in the level of conflict
ƒ Survey participants about regulatory adaptability/flexibility
ƒ Survey participants about cost to participate in fishery
ƒ Percent of total fisheries revenue spent on participation costs.
ƒ Survey participants about time spent participating in process,
understanding process, attending meetings.
ƒ Number and/or frequency (time between) of amendments and
frameworks per year
ƒ Size of amendments/frameworks
ƒ Survey participants about perception of management complexity
Proposed Approach (some or all of these may be used)
ƒ Develop compliance index based on enforcement statistics
ƒ Measure with existing monitoring data
ƒ Survey participants about perception of compliance
ƒ Survey participants about going beyond the regulations and engaging
in other activities that improve the condition of the stock
Proposed Approach (some or all of these may be used)
ƒ Survey participants about health insurance coverage
ƒ Develop index based on community level health statistics
ƒ Develop index based on community level crime, poverty,
unemployment, education, and conflict
ƒ Profile relevant ports
ƒ Survey participants about job satisfaction
ƒ Survey participants about social networks

7

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

relationships
Safety

ƒ Number of fisheries-related injuries/hospitalizations*
ƒ Number of fisheries-related fatalities*
ƒ Number of vessels lost*
ƒ Damage costs*
ƒ Survey participants about perception of riskier/safer fishing practices
*Variables agreed upon nationally by NMFS social scientist working group.
Implementing the performance monitoring and evaluation plan
Some of the indicators in the table above can be obtained or calculated from existing data to at least some extent.
For example, NMFS landings databases include vessel tonnage, gear, species, pounds and market categories landed,
and port of landing. Permit databases include permit owner name and residence, fisheries for which permits are held,
and names and demographic data on vessel captains. An add-on to the permits provides information on fixed costs
(e.g., permit fees, association dues, maintenance, communications, interest, mooring, travel, automobile, office
space) and observer logs note trip costs (e.g., food, fuel, oil, water, bait, ice, supplies, gear damage) and captain
years of experience. Vessel trip reports provide number of crew per trip, discards, time and location of trips and gear
used. There are also databases on accidents and sinkings, and on infractions. And, of course, details are available on
the number, type and length of FMPs and other regulations. Further, there are U.S. Census data by community on
factors such as poverty rates, population levels and educational attainment. These variables can be used to begin
crafting a number of the indicators in Table 2, e.g., 1) revenue per active vessel for profitability and 2) productivity
(Financial Viability); 1) total number of fisherman days for employment trends and 2) revenue by vessel size and
community/geographic location for changes in location and/or concentration of landings - or residence of quota
holders (Distributional Outcomes); number and/or frequency of amendments and frameworks per year (time
between) for management complexity (Governance); number of regulatory infractions for compliance
(Stewardship), and 1) number of vessel accidents and 2) poverty rates for health status (Well-being).
Effectively monitoring other performance measures, however, requires the collection of new data. In FY10, limited
SSB resources are being used to create two new time series surveys to cover a range of basic sociocultural variables:
one for vessel owners (permit holders), who are often captains, and the other for vessel crew. Given that the latter
population is largely unknown (there is no crew registry in the Northeast U.S. nor are crew unionized or otherwise
organized), ethnographic work will be conducted to identify the best means of conducting research on this
population as well as identifying early impacts of catch share programs on this group. The surveys will build in part
on two pilot surveys already in progress. One is a social capital survey of all groundfish permit holders. The other is
a well-being/job satisfaction/environmental stewardship survey being conducted in Maine, New Hampshire,
Massachusetts, and Rhode Island, and targeting current and former fishermen as well as some fishing household
members and shore side support employees. The fishing vessel fixed cost survey will also be revised in 2010/2011,
providing the opportunity to collect additional economic information related to performance measures.
More such initiatives will be needed in order to implement the full plan over time. Additionally, there are areas of
research where surveys are impractical or inappropriate due to the nature of the research question or the population
involved. To begin to fill these gaps, additional work is underway including research on consolidation and the
concept of excessive shares, and the on-going collection of oral histories related to fisheries stakeholders to
document the human experience in fisheries. These oral histories are or will eventually be (depending on
confidentiality) housed in an SSB/ Headquarters Office of Science and Technology collaborative database Voices
from the Fisheries (VFF) at http://www.st.nmfs.noaa.gov/voicesfromthefisheries/.
Challenges, Limitations & Opportunities
In implementing indicators created with both existing data and new data, we face significant challenges. Not all
existing databases were created with social science research in mind, and so are not always set up as needed for our
use. Even where data are not so problematic there are technical challenges. For instance, constructing productivity
indices requires data on vessel inputs (e.g., length, horsepower, crew size) and outputs (i.e., what is caught). Often
these data are not available for all vessels, and the analyst needs to decide which input data to use. Because fishing
vessels are typically multi-product firms (i.e., they catch more than one species), additional decisions are needed to
aggregate outputs into appropriate species groups. Then, questions need to be addressed such as whether there are

8

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

enough vessels in a group to construct an index and how to choose the appropriate base year for comparison
purposes. Thus, although in principle methods and data exist to construct economic indicators such as productivity
change, additional research may be necessary to determine how to best construct the indicators.
In addition to technical challenges, bureaucratic processes must be adhered to when involving human subjects in
research. These often lengthen the research process substantially. For example, in order to implement a survey with
more than nine subjects, the survey must undergo a lengthy (up to 12-18 month) approval process by the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB) under the Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA; 44 USC § 3501 et seq.). This can be
frustrating when baselines are lost or other key moments cannot be captured within an ideal timeline.
As mentioned previously, a significant challenge we face in reaching crew is that there is no sample frame from
which to design a standard survey sampling approach. There is no registry of crew that would provide the size of
the population or contact information. Creative sampling approaches, possibly based on intercept surveys, must be
designed in order to obtain a representative sample of this unknown population. In conjunction with such
approaches to the crew survey, the SSB is exploring the idea of a crew registry with the NMFS Northeast Regional
Office and the Councils. Additionally, outreach efforts continue with crew, as mentioned previously, to determine
the best method of reaching out to this segment of the industry over time.
Finally, while the SSB is well placed to conduct the ongoing data collection necessary for long-term monitoring and
trend analysis, this is difficult in a constantly changing funding environment. The SSB, just as the rest of the federal
government, must wait until final budgets are passed through Congress each year before committing funds. Even if
funding amounts are sufficient, they may arrive at too late a date to be used for certain types of activities. Effective
long-term monitoring will require sufficient and sustained funding.
The NEFSC has long been interested in better long-term monitoring and evaluation of Northeast fisheries in general.
We need to know not only what the actual impacts of catch shares are, but how these compare to the outcomes of
other management regimes. With the establishment of our performance measures and associated indicators, the SSB
is now poised to evaluate these outcomes in the Northeast in the most scientifically defensible manner. Our findings
can then serve as guideposts for future management planning.
By working with a variety of stakeholder groups, the SSB has developed a set of performance measures and
associated indicators that are salient to all parties. As we proceed, effective communication of results to all
stakeholders will be key in ensuring that sound social science is used to improve the quality of fisheries management
in general and catch share programs in particular.
REFERENCES
Arnason, Ragnar, 2008, Iceland’s ITQ system creates new wealth, The Electronic Journal of Sustainable
Development 1(2), pp. 35-41. http://www.icelandcrash.com/ragnararna.pdf (accessed June 23, 2010)
Arnason, Ragnar, 2005, Property rights in fisheries: Iceland’s experience with ITQs, Reviews in Fish Biology and
Fisheries, 15, pp. 243–264.
Bradshaw, Matt, 2004, A combination of state and market through ITQs in the Tasmanian commercial rock lobster
fishery: The tail wagging the dog?, Fisheries Research, 67(2), pp. 99-109.
Branch, Trevor A., 2009, How do individual transferable quotas affect marine ecosystems?, Fish and Fisheries,
10(1), pp. 39-57. Online publication date: 1-Sep-2008.
Branch, Trevor A., Ray Hilborn, Alan C. Haynie, Gavin Fay, Lucy Flynn, Jennifer Griffiths, Kristin N. Marshall,
Jeffrey K. Randall, Jennifer M. Scheuerell, Eric J. Ward, and Mark Young, 2006, Fleet dynamics and
fishermen behavior: Lessons for fisheries managers, Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Science,
63(7), pp. 1647–1668.
Brandt, Sylvia, 2005, The equity debate: Distributional impacts of Individual Transferable Quotas, Ocean & Coastal
Management, 48, pp. 15–30.
Brandt, Sylvia and Ning Ding, 2008, Impact of property rights on labor contracts in commercial fisheries, Ocean &
Coastal Management, 51(11), pp. 740-748.
Brickman, Philip, Dan Coates and Ronnie Janoff-Bulman, 1978, Lottery winners and accident victims: Is happiness
relative?, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 36(8), pp. 917-92.

9

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

Bromley, Daniel W., 2005, Purging the frontier from our mind: Crafting a new fisheries policy, Reviews in Fish
Biology and Fisheries, 15, pp. 217-229.
Charles, Anthony, Arthur Bull, John Kearney and Chris Milley, 2007, Community-based fisheries in the Canadian
Maritimes, pp. 274-305, Fisheries Management: Progress towards Sustainability, Tim R. McClanahan and
Juan Carlos Castilla (Editors), Oxford: Blackwell. 352p.
Charles, Anthony, Chris Burbidge, Heather Boyd and Amanda Lavers, 2009, Fisheries and the Marine Environment
in Nova Scotia: Searching for Sustainability and Resilience, Halifax, Nova Scotia: GPI Atlantic.
http://www.gpiatlantic.org/pdf/fisheries/fisheries_2008.pdf (accessed 17 March 2010)
Chu, Cindy, 2008, Thirty years later: The global growth of ITQs and their influence on stock status in marine
fisheries, Fish and Fisheries, 10(2), pp. 1–14.
Clay, Patricia M. and Julia Olson, 2008, Defining ‘fishing communities’: Vulnerability and the Magnuson-Stevens
Fisheries Conservation and Management Act, Special section on Vulnerability and resilience in the
fisheries, Patricia Pinto da Silva and Madeleine Hall- Arber (Guest Editors), Human Ecology Review,
15(2), pp. 143-160.
Clark, Colin W., 1980, Towards a predictive model for the economic regulation of commercial fisheries, Canadian
Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Science, 37(7), pp. 1111-1129.
Costello, Christopher, Steven D. Gaines, and John Lynham, 2008, Can catch shares prevent fisheries collapse?,
Science 321(5896), pp. 1678 – 1681.
Dupont, Diane P. and R. Quentin Grafton, 2001, Multi-Species Individual Transferable Quotas: The Scotia-Fundy
mobile gear Ground-fishery, Marine Resource Economics, 15(3), pp. 205-220.
Environmental Defense Fund (EDF), 2009, Draft Catch Shares Manual.
http://www.edf.org/documents/10400_catch_shares_design_manual_09.09.09.pdf, (accessed February 25,
2010)
Environmental Defense Fund (EDF), 2007, Catch Shares (LAPPs): A Promising Solution, a New Way toRevive
Fisheries and Fishing Communities. July 25. http://www.edf.org/page.cfm?tagID=3332 (accessed March
17, 2010)
Essington, Timothy E., 2010, Ecological indicators display reduced variation in North American catch share
fisheries, PNAS, 107(2), pp. 754–759.
Eythórsson, Einar, 1996, Theory and practice of ITQs in Iceland: Privatization of common fishing rights, Marine
Policy, 20(3), pp. 269–81.
Eythórsson, Einar, 2000, A decade of ITQ-management in Icelandic fisheries: Consolidation without consensus,
Marine Policy, 24(6), pp. 483-492.
Fox, Kevin J., R. Quentin Grafton., James Kirkley, and Dale Squires, 2002, Property Rights in a Fishery:
Regulatory Change and Firm Performance, Economics and Environment Network. 26p.
http://een.anu.edu.au/download_files/een0205.pdf (accessed June 23, 2010)
Gauvin, John R., John M. Ward, and Edward E. Burgess, 1994, Description and evaluation of the wreckfish
(Polyprion americanus) fishery under Individual Transferable Quotas, Marine Resource Economics, 9(2),
pp. 99-118.
Geen, Gerry and Mark Nayar, 1989, Individual Transferable Quotas and the Southern Bluefin Tuna Fishery:
Economic Impact, Occasional Paper 105, ABARE, AGPS, Canberra. 40p.
http://www.abare.gov.au/publications_html/fisheries/archive/89_bluefintuna.pdf (accessed June 23, 2010)
Gordon, H. Scott, 1954, The economic theory of a common property resource, Journal of Political Economy, 62(2),
pp. 124-142.
Government Accounting Office (GAO), 2006, Fisheries Management: Core Principles and a Strategic Approach
Would Enhance Stakeholder Participation in Developing Quota-based Programs, GAO-06-289. 50p.
http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d06289.pdf (accessed 23 March 2010)
Grafton, R. Quentin, Ragnar Árnason, Trond Bjørndal, David Campbell, Harry F. Campbell, Colin W. Clark, Robin
Connor, Diane P. Dupont, Rögnvaldur Hannesson, Ray Hilborn, James E. Kirkley, Tom Kompas, Daniel E.
Lane, Gordon R. Munro, Sean Pascoe, Dale Squires, Stein Ivar Steinshamn, Bruce R. Turris, and Quinn
Weninger, 2006, Incentive-based approaches to sustainable fisheries, Canadian Journal of Fisheries and
Aquatic Science, 63(3), pp. 699–710.
Grafton, R. Quentin, 1996, Experiences with Individual Transferable Quotas: An overview, The Canadian Journal
of Economics, vol. 29, Special Issue: Part 1 (Apr.), pp. S135-S138.
Graham, Carol, 2009, Happiness Around the World: The Paradox of Happy Peasants and Miserable Millionaires,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.

10

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

Gruenwald, Paul J., Andrew J. Treno, Gail Taff, and Michael Klitzner, 1997, Measuring Community Indicators: A
Systems Approach to Drug and Alcohol Problems. Applied Social Research Methods Series, vol. 45.
Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. 114p.
Hermansen, Øystein and Bent Dreyer, 2010, Challenging spatial and seasonal distribution of fish landings—The
experiences from rural community quotas in Norway, Marine Policy, 34 (3), pp. 567–574.
Jacob, Stephen and Michael Jepson, 2009, Creating a community context for the Fishery Stock Sustainability Index,
Fisheries, 34(5), pp. 228-231.
James, Michelle, 2008, Cooperative management of the Geoduck and Horse-clam fishery in British Columbia, pp.
397–406, Ralph Townsend, Ross Shotton and Hiro Uchida (Editors), Case Studies in Fisheries SelfGovernance, FAO Technical Paper No. 504, FAO. Rome, Italy. 451p.
Jepson, Michael and Stephen Jacob, 2007, Social indicator measurements of vulnerability for Gulf Coast fishing
communities, NAPA Bulletin, 28(1), pp. 57-68.
Johnston, Robert J. and Jon G. Sutinen, 2009, One Last Chance: The Economic Case for a New Approach to
Fisheries Management in New England, The Pew Environment Group, Washington, D.C. 21p.
http://www.pewtrusts.org/uploadedFiles/wwwpewtrustsorg/Reports/Protecting_ocean_life/Johnston_Sutine
n_2009.pdf (accessed July 13, 2010)
Keiley, Emily E., 2010, Report of the Northeast fisheries Summit. Sponsored by the City of New Bedford,
University of Massachusetts Dartmouth, and the Massachusetts Marine Fisheries Institute.
Kompas, Tom and Uong Nhu Che, 2003, Efficiency Gains and Cost Reductions from Individual Transferable
Quotas: A Stochastic Cost Frontier for the Australian South East Fishery, Asia Pacific School of
Economics and Government Working Paper 03-6.
http://www.crawford.anu.edu.au/degrees/idec/working_papers/IDEC03-6.pdf (accessed June 24, 2004)
Langdon, Steve J., 2008, The community quota program in the Gulf of Alaska: A vehicle for Alaska Native village
sustainability?, pp. 155-194 , Marie E. Lowe and Courtney Carothers (Editors), Enclosing the Fisheries:
People, Places, and Power, Bethesda, MD: American Fisheries Society, Symposium 68.
Macinko, Seth and William Whitmore, 2009, A New England dilemma: Thinking sectors through, Final Report to
the Massachusetts Division of Marine Fisheries.
http://www.uri.edu/personal/macinko/NewEnglandDilemmaFinal.pdf (accessed July 13, 2010)
Mahon, Robin, Lucia Fanning, Patrick McConney and Richard Pollnac, 2010, Governance characteristics of Large
Marine Ecosystems, Marine Policy, 34(5), pp. 919-927.
Mansfield, Becky, 2007, Property, markets, and dispossession: The Western Alaska Community Development
Quota as neoliberalism, social justice, both, and neither, Antipode, 39(3), pp. 479-499.
Maurstad, Anita, 2000, To fish or not to fish: Small-scale fishing and changing regulations of the cod fishery in
Northern Norway, Human Organization, 59(1), pp. 37-47.
McCay, Bonnie J., 2004, ITQs and community: An essay on environmental governance, Agricultural and Resource
Economics Review, 33(2), pp. 162-170.
Meridian Institute, with MRAG Americas Inc., 2010, Catch Shares in New England: Key Questions and Lessons
Learned from Existing Programs
http://www.savingseafood.org/images/documents/regulation/catch_share_in_new_england_final_feb_2010.
pdf( accessed February 23, 2010)
North Atlantic Marine Alliance (NAMA), 2005, Northeast Region’s Vision for the Future of the Groundfish Fishery
Fleet: A Comprehensive Report, Fleet Visioning Project, North Atlantic Marine Alliance. Gloucester, MA.
December. 80p. http://namanet.org/files/documents/ComprehensiveFleetVisioningReport.pdf (accessed
June 22, 2010)
Olson, Julia, In Prep., Understanding and contextualizing social impacts from the privatization of fisheries: An
overview. Under journal review.
National Research Council (NRC), 1999, Sharing the Fish: Toward a National Policy on Individual Fishing Quotas,
Washington, DC: National Academy Press.
National Research Council (NRC), 2003, Cooperative Research in the National Marine Fisheries Service.
Washington, DC.: National Research Council Press.
Phillips, Gregory, Lorne Kriwoken, and Peter Hay, 2002, Private property and public interest in fisheries
management: The Tasmanian rock lobster fishery, Marine Policy, 26(6), pp. 459-469.
Pinto da Silva, Patricia, 2004. From common property to co-management; Lessons from Brazil’s first Maritime
Extractive Reserve, Marine Policy, 28 (5), pp. 419-428.
Plante, Janice, 2010, Scientists study ‘human dimensions’ of sectors. IFQs, catch shares; industry participation
needed, Commercial Fisheries News, April, pp. 13A-15A.

11

IIFET 2010 Montpellier Proceedings

Pollnac, Richard and John J. Poggie, 2008, Happiness, Well-being and psychocultural adaptation to the stresses
associated with marine fishing, Special section on Vulnerability and resilience in the fisheries, Patricia
Pinto da Silva and Madeleine Hall-Arber (Guest Editors), Human Ecology Review 15(2), pp. 194-200.
(accessed 20 August 2009).
Pollnac, Richard B., Susan Abbott-Jamieson, Courtland Smith, Marc L. Miller, Patricia M. Clay, and Bryan Oles,
2006[2008], Toward a model for fisheries Social Impact Assessment, Marine Fisheries Review, 65(1-4),
pp. 1-18.
Scott, Anthony D., 1955, The fishery: The objectives of sole ownership, Journal of Political Economics, 63, pp.
116–124.
Shotton, Ross (Editor), 2000, Use of Property Rights in Fisheries Management, FAO Fisheries Technical Paper
404/1 & 2. Rome, FAO.
Smith, Courtland and Patricia M. Clay, 2010, Measuring Subjective and Objective Well-being: Analyses from five
commercial fisheries, Human Organization, 69(2), pp. 158-168.
Sigler, Michael F. and Chris R. Lunsford, 2001, Effects of individual quotas on catching efficiency and spawning
potential in the Alaska sablefish fishery, Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences, 58(7), pp.
1300-1312.
Stiglitz, Joseph, Amartya Sen, and Jean-Paul Fitoussi, 2009, Report by the Commission on the Measurement of
Economic Performance and Social Progress. http:/www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr (accessed March 19, 2010)
Townsend, Ralph, Roy Shotton, and Hiro Uchida (Editors), 2008, Case Studies in Fisheries Self-Governance, FAO
Fisheries Technical Paper No. 504. Rome, FAO. 451p.
Trondsen, Torbjørn, 2004, Toward market orientation: The role of auctioning Individual Seasonal Quotas (ISQ),
Marine Policy, 28(5), pp. 375-382.
Tuler, Seth, Julian Agyeman, Patricia Pinto da Silva, Karen Roth LoRusso and Rebecca Kay, 2008, Improving the
social sustainability of fisheries management by assessing stakeholder vulnerability, Special section on
Vulnerability and resilience in the fisheries, Patricia Pinto da Silva and Madeleine Hall-Arber (Guest
Editors), Human Ecology Review ,15(2), pp. 171-184. (accessed 20 August 2009).
Windle Matthew J.S., Barbara Neis, Stephen Bornstein, Marian Binkley, and Pablo Navarro, 2008, Fishing
occupational health and safety: A comparison of regulatory regimes and safety outcomes in six countries,
Marine Policy, 32(4), pp. 701-710.
Wingard, John D., 2000, Community transferable quotas: Internalizing externalities and minimizing social impacts
of fisheries management, Human Organization, 59(1), pp. 48-57.
World Bank, 2008, The Sunken Billions. The Economic Justification for Fisheries Reform. Washington, DC:
Agriculture and Rural Development Department of The World Bank. 80p.
Worm, Boris, Ray Hilborn, Julia K. Baum, Trevor A. Branch, Jeremy S. Collie, Christopher Costello, Michael J.
Fogarty, Elizabeth A. Fulton, Jeffrey A. Hutchings, Simon Jennings, Olaf P. Jensen, Heike K. Lotze,
Pamela M. Mace, Tim R. McClanahan, Cóilín Minto, Stephen R. Palumbi, Ana M. Parma, Daniel Ricard,
Andrew A. Rosenberg, Reg Watson, and Dirk Zeller, 2009, Rebuilding global fisheries, Science 325(5940),
pp. 578-585.
ENDNOTES

1

http://www.nmfs.noaa.gov/sfa/domes_fish/catchshare/docs/draft_noaa_cs_policy.pdf (accessed 23 Mar 2010)
http://www.nmfs.noaa.gov/sfa/domes_fish/catchshare/index.htm (accessed May 19, 2010).
3
This FMP covers Winter Flounder (Blackback, Lemon Sole) (Pleuronectes americanus), Atlantic Cod (Gadus
morhua), Dab (American Plaice) (Hippoglossoides platessoides), Haddock (Melanogrammus aeglefinus), Ocean
Pout (Macrozoarces americanus), Pollock (Pollachius virens), Redfish (Sebastes fasciatus), Red Hake (Ling)
(Urophycis chuss), Windowpane Flounder (Sand Flounder) (Scophthalmus aquosus), Witch Flounder (Gray Sole)
(Glyptocephalus cynoglossus), Yellowtail Flounder (Limanda ferruginea), White hake (Urophycis tenuis), Atlantic
Halibut (Hippoglossus hippoglossus) and Atlantic Wolffish (Anarhichas lupus).
4
http://www.nmfs.noaa.gov/msa2005/docs/MSA_amended_msa%20_20070112_FINAL.pdf (accessed 6 Mar 2008)
5
http://www.northeastconsortium.org/index.shtml (accessed Jun 25, 2010)
6
http://www.nefsc.noaa.gov/read/socialsci/catchshares/ (accessed 23 Mar 2010) - we chose to place “catch shares”
in the path as we thought it might capture a higher number of casual searches.
7
See report at http://www.gmri.org/community_socioeconomics.
2

12


File Typeapplication/pdf
File TitleLab-Scale Demonstration of the UREX+ Process
AuthorGeorge Vandegrift
File Modified2011-01-10
File Created2010-10-04

© 2024 OMB.report | Privacy Policy